Skip to ContentGo to accessibility pageKeyboard shortcuts menu
OpenStax Logo
Principles of Microeconomics 3e

5.1 Price Elasticity of Demand and Price Elasticity of Supply

Principles of Microeconomics 3e5.1 Price Elasticity of Demand and Price Elasticity of Supply

Learning Objectives

By the end of this section, you will be able to:
  • Calculate the price elasticity of demand
  • Calculate the price elasticity of supply

Both the demand and supply curve show the relationship between price and the number of units demanded or supplied. Price elasticity is the ratio between the percentage change in the quantity demanded (Qd) or supplied (Qs) and the corresponding percent change in price. The price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the quantity demanded of a good or service divided by the percentage change in the price. The price elasticity of supply is the percentage change in quantity supplied divided by the percentage change in price.

We can usefully divide elasticities into three broad categories: elastic, inelastic, and unitary. Because price and quantity demanded move in opposite directions, price elasticity of demand is always a negative number. Therefore, price elasticity of demand is usually reported as its absolute value, without a negative sign. The summary in Table 5.1 is assuming absolute values for price elasticity of demand. An elastic demand or elastic supply is one in which the elasticity is greater than one, indicating a high responsiveness to changes in price. Elasticities that are less than one indicate low responsiveness to price changes and correspond to inelastic demand or inelastic supply. Unitary elasticities indicate proportional responsiveness of either demand or supply, as Table 5.1 summarizes.

If . . . Then . . . And It Is Called . . .
% change in quantity>% change in price% change in quantity>% change in price % change in quantity% change in price>1% change in quantity% change in price>1 Elastic
% change in quantity=% change in price% change in quantity=% change in price % change in quantity% change in price=1% change in quantity% change in price=1 Unitary
% change in quantity<% change in price% change in quantity<% change in price % change in quantity% change in price<1% change in quantity% change in price<1 Inelastic
Table 5.1 Elastic, Inelastic, and Unitary: Three Cases of Elasticity

Link It Up

Before we delve into the details of elasticity, enjoy this article on elasticity and ticket prices at the Super Bowl.

To calculate elasticity along a demand or supply curve economists use the average percent change in both quantity and price. This is called the Midpoint Method for Elasticity, and is represented in the following equations:

% change in quantity=Q2Q1Q2+ Q1/2 × 100% change in price=P2 P1P2+ P1/2 × 100 % change in quantity=Q2Q1Q2+ Q1/2 × 100% change in price=P2 P1P2+ P1/2 × 100

The advantage of the Midpoint Method is that one obtains the same elasticity between two price points whether there is a price increase or decrease. This is because the formula uses the same base (average quantity and average price) for both cases.

Calculating Price Elasticity of Demand

Let’s calculate the elasticity between points A and B and between points G and H as Figure 5.2 shows.

This graph illustrates a downward-sloping demand curve. Different price and quantity demanded combinations are shown, with different letters representing those points. The top left combination is point H, a price of 130 dollars and quantity of 1600. The next point is point G, a price of 120 dollars and quantity of 1800. Moving down the demand curve the last two points illustrated are B and A. B is price of 70 dollars and quantity of 2800. A is a price of 60 dollars and quantity of 3000. These points and their different prices and quantities can be used to calculate price elasticity of demand.
Figure 5.2 Calculating the Price Elasticity of Demand We calculate the price elasticity of demand as the percentage change in quantity divided by the percentage change in price.

First, apply the formula to calculate the elasticity as price decreases from $70 at point B to $60 at point A:

% change in quantity=3,0002,800(3,000+2,800)/2 × 100=2002,900 × 100=6.9% change in price=6070(60+70)/2 × 100=–1065 × 100=–15.4Price Elasticity of Demand=    6.9%–15.4%=0.45% change in quantity=3,0002,800(3,000+2,800)/2 × 100=2002,900 × 100=6.9% change in price=6070(60+70)/2 × 100=–1065 × 100=–15.4Price Elasticity of Demand=    6.9%–15.4%=0.45

Therefore, the elasticity of demand between these two points is     6.9%–15.4%    6.9%–15.4% which is 0.45, an amount smaller than one, showing that the demand is inelastic in this interval. Price elasticities of demand are always negative since price and quantity demanded always move in opposite directions (on the demand curve). By convention, we always talk about price elasticities of demand as positive numbers. Mathematically, we take the absolute value of the result. We will ignore this detail from now on, while remembering to interpret elasticities as positive numbers.

This means that, along the demand curve between point B and A, if the price changes by 1%, the quantity demanded will change by 0.45%. A change in the price will result in a smaller percentage change in the quantity demanded. For example, a 10% increase in the price will result in only a 4.5% decrease in quantity demanded. A 10% decrease in the price will result in only a 4.5% increase in the quantity demanded. Price elasticities of demand are negative numbers indicating that the demand curve is downward sloping, but we read them as absolute values. The following Work It Out feature will walk you through calculating the price elasticity of demand.

Work It Out

Finding the Price Elasticity of Demand

Calculate the price elasticity of demand using the data in Figure 5.2 for an increase in price from G to H. Has the elasticity increased or decreased?

Step 1. We know that:

Price Elasticity of Demand=% change in quantity% change in pricePrice Elasticity of Demand=% change in quantity% change in price

Step 2. From the Midpoint Formula we know that:

change in quantity=Q2Q1(Q2+Q1)/2 × 100change in price=P2P1(P2+P1)/2 × 100change in quantity=Q2Q1(Q2+Q1)/2 × 100change in price=P2P1(P2+P1)/2 × 100

Step 3. So we can use the values provided in the figure in each equation:

% change in quantity=1,6001,800(1,600+1,800)/2 × 100=–2001,700 × 100=–11.76% change in price=130120(130+120)/2 × 100=10125 × 100=8.0% change in quantity=1,6001,800(1,600+1,800)/2 × 100=–2001,700 × 100=–11.76% change in price=130120(130+120)/2 × 100=10125 × 100=8.0

Step 4. Then, we can use those values to determine the price elasticity of demand:

Price Elasticity of Demand=% change in quantity% change in price=–11.768=1.47Price Elasticity of Demand=% change in quantity% change in price=–11.768=1.47

Therefore, the elasticity of demand from G to is H 1.47. The magnitude of the elasticity has increased (in absolute value) as we moved up along the demand curve from points A to B. Recall that the elasticity between these two points was 0.45. Demand was inelastic between points A and B and elastic between points G and H. This shows us that price elasticity of demand changes at different points along a straight-line demand curve.

Calculating the Price Elasticity of Supply

Assume that an apartment rents for $650 per month and at that price the landlord rents 10,000 units as Figure 5.3 shows. When the price increases to $700 per month, the landlord supplies 13,000 units into the market. By what percentage does apartment supply increase? What is the price sensitivity?

The graph shows an upward sloping line that represents the supply of apartment rentals.
Figure 5.3 Price Elasticity of Supply We calculate the price elasticity of supply as the percentage change in quantity divided by the percentage change in price.

Using the Midpoint Method,

% change in quantity=13,00010,000(13,000+10,000)/2 × 100=3,00011,500 × 100=26.1% change in price=$700$650($700+$650)/2 × 100=50675 × 100=7.4Price Elasticity of Supply=26.1%  7.4%=3.53% change in quantity=13,00010,000(13,000+10,000)/2 × 100=3,00011,500 × 100=26.1% change in price=$700$650($700+$650)/2 × 100=50675 × 100=7.4Price Elasticity of Supply=26.1%  7.4%=3.53

Again, as with the elasticity of demand, the elasticity of supply is not followed by any units. Elasticity is a ratio of one percentage change to another percentage change—nothing more—and we read it as an absolute value. In this case, a 1% rise in price causes an increase in quantity supplied of 3.5%. The greater than one elasticity of supply means that the percentage change in quantity supplied will be greater than a one percent price change. If you're starting to wonder if the concept of slope fits into this calculation, read the following Clear It Up box.

Clear It Up

Is the elasticity the slope?

It is a common mistake to confuse the slope of either the supply or demand curve with its elasticity. The slope is the rate of change in units along the curve, or the rise/run (change in y over the change in x). For example, in Figure 5.2, at each point shown on the demand curve, price drops by $10 and the number of units demanded increases by 200 compared to the point to its left. The slope is –10/200 along the entire demand curve and does not change. The price elasticity, however, changes along the curve. Elasticity between points A and B was 0.45 and increased to 1.47 between points G and H. Elasticity is the percentage change, which is a different calculation from the slope and has a different meaning.

When we are at the upper end of a demand curve, where price is high and the quantity demanded is low, a small change in the quantity demanded, even in, say, one unit, is pretty big in percentage terms. A change in price of, say, a dollar, is going to be much less important in percentage terms than it would have been at the bottom of the demand curve. Likewise, at the bottom of the demand curve, that one unit change when the quantity demanded is high will be small as a percentage.

Thus, at one end of the demand curve, where we have a large percentage change in quantity demanded over a small percentage change in price, the elasticity value would be high, or demand would be relatively elastic. Even with the same change in the price and the same change in the quantity demanded, at the other end of the demand curve the quantity is much higher, and the price is much lower, so the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller and the percentage change in price is much higher. That means at the bottom of the curve we'd have a small numerator over a large denominator, so the elasticity measure would be much lower, or inelastic.

As we move along the demand curve, the values for quantity and price go up or down, depending on which way we are moving, so the percentages for, say, a $1 difference in price or a one unit difference in quantity, will change as well, which means the ratios of those percentages and hence the elasticity will change.

Order a print copy

As an Amazon Associate we earn from qualifying purchases.

Citation/Attribution

This book may not be used in the training of large language models or otherwise be ingested into large language models or generative AI offerings without OpenStax's permission.

Want to cite, share, or modify this book? This book uses the Creative Commons Attribution License and you must attribute OpenStax.

Attribution information
  • If you are redistributing all or part of this book in a print format, then you must include on every physical page the following attribution:
    Access for free at https://openstax.org/books/principles-microeconomics-3e/pages/1-introduction
  • If you are redistributing all or part of this book in a digital format, then you must include on every digital page view the following attribution:
    Access for free at https://openstax.org/books/principles-microeconomics-3e/pages/1-introduction
Citation information

© Jan 23, 2024 OpenStax. Textbook content produced by OpenStax is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License . The OpenStax name, OpenStax logo, OpenStax book covers, OpenStax CNX name, and OpenStax CNX logo are not subject to the Creative Commons license and may not be reproduced without the prior and express written consent of Rice University.