Skip to ContentGo to accessibility pageKeyboard shortcuts menu
OpenStax Logo
Principles of Economics 3e

31.1 How Government Borrowing Affects Investment and the Trade Balance

Principles of Economics 3e31.1 How Government Borrowing Affects Investment and the Trade Balance

Learning Objectives

By the end of this section, you will be able to:

  • Explain the national saving and investment identity in terms of demand and supply
  • Evaluate the role of budget surpluses and trade surpluses in national saving and investment identity

When governments are borrowers in financial markets, there are three possible sources for the funds from a macroeconomic point of view: (1) households might save more; (2) private firms might borrow less; and (3) the additional funds for government borrowing might come from outside the country, from foreign financial investors. Let’s begin with a review of why one of these three options must occur, and then explore how interest rates and exchange rates adjust to these connections.

The National Saving and Investment Identity

The national saving and investment identity, which we first introduced in The International Trade and Capital Flows chapter, provides a framework for showing the relationships between the sources of demand and supply in financial capital markets. The identity begins with a statement that must always hold true: the quantity of financial capital supplied in the market must equal the quantity of financial capital demanded.

The U.S. economy has two main sources for financial capital: private savings from inside the U.S. economy and public savings.

Total savings = Private savings (S) + Public savings (T – G)Total savings = Private savings (S) + Public savings (T – G)

These include the inflow of foreign financial capital from abroad. The inflow of savings from abroad is, by definition, equal to the trade deficit, as we explained in The International Trade and Capital Flows chapter. We can write this inflow of foreign investment capital as imports (M) minus exports (X). There are also two main sources of demand for financial capital: private sector investment (I) and government borrowing. Government borrowing in any given year is equal to the budget deficit, which we can write as the difference between government spending (G) and net taxes (T). Let’s call this equation 1.

Quantity supplied of financial capital = Quantity demanded of financial capitalPrivate savings + Inflow of foreign savings = Private investment + Government budget deficitS + (M – X) = I + (G –T)Quantity supplied of financial capital = Quantity demanded of financial capitalPrivate savings + Inflow of foreign savings = Private investment + Government budget deficitS + (M – X) = I + (G –T)

Governments often spend more than they receive in taxes and, therefore, public savings (T – G) is negative. This causes a need to borrow money in the amount of (G – T) instead of adding to the nation’s savings. If this is the case, we can view governments as demanders of financial capital instead of suppliers. In algebraic terms, we can rewrite the national savings and investment identity like this:

Private investment = Private savings + Public savings + Trade deficitI = S + (T – G) + (M – X)Private investment = Private savings + Public savings + Trade deficitI = S + (T – G) + (M – X)

Let’s call this equation 2. We must accompany a change in any part of the national saving and investment identity by offsetting changes in at least one other part of the equation because we assume that the equality of quantity supplied and quantity demanded always holds. If the government budget deficit changes, then either private saving or investment or the trade balance—or some combination of the three—must change as well. Figure 31.2 shows the possible effects.

Following from the national savings and investment identity, charts (a) and (b) show what happens to investment, private savings, and the trade deficit when the budget deficit rises (or the budget surplus falls). (a) If the budget deficit rises (or the government budget surplus falls), the results could be (1) domestic private investment falls or (2) private savings rise or (3) the trade deficit increases (or a trade surplus diminishes). The opposite results of each are achieved when the budget deficit falls (or the budget surplus rises) as shown in image (b).
Figure 31.2 Effects of Change in Budget Surplus or Deficit on Investment, Savings, and The Trade Balance Chart (a) shows the potential results when the budget deficit rises (or budget surplus falls). Chart (b) shows the potential results when the budget deficit falls (or budget surplus rises).

What about Budget Surpluses and Trade Surpluses?

The national saving and investment identity must always hold true because, by definition, the quantity supplied and quantity demanded in the financial capital market must always be equal. However, the formula will look somewhat different if the government budget is in deficit rather than surplus or if the balance of trade is in surplus rather than deficit. For example, in 1999 and 2000, the U.S. government had budget surpluses, although the economy was still experiencing trade deficits. When the government was running budget surpluses, it was acting as a saver rather than a borrower, and supplying rather than demanding financial capital. As a result, we would write the national saving and investment identity during this time as:

Quantity supplied of financial capital =Quantity demanded of financial capital Private savings + Trade deficit + Government surplus= Private investment S + (M – X) + (T – G) = IQuantity supplied of financial capital =Quantity demanded of financial capital Private savings + Trade deficit + Government surplus= Private investment S + (M – X) + (T – G) = I

Let's call this equation 3. Notice that this expression is mathematically the same as equation 2 except the savings and investment sides of the identity have simply flipped sides.

During the 1960s, the U.S. government was often running a budget deficit, but the economy was typically running trade surpluses. Since a trade surplus means that an economy is experiencing a net outflow of financial capital, we would write the national saving and investment identity as:

Quantity supplied of financial capital=Quantity demanded of financial capitalPrivate savings=Private investment + Outflow of foreign savings + Government budget deficitS=I + (X – M) + (G – T)Quantity supplied of financial capital=Quantity demanded of financial capitalPrivate savings=Private investment + Outflow of foreign savings + Government budget deficitS=I + (X – M) + (G – T)

Instead of the balance of trade representing part of the supply of financial capital, which occurs with a trade deficit, a trade surplus represents an outflow of financial capital leaving the domestic economy and invested elsewhere in the world.

Quantity supplied of financial capital=Quantity demanded of financial capital demandPrivate savings=Private investment + Government budget deficit + Trade surplusS=I + (G – T) + (X – M) Quantity supplied of financial capital=Quantity demanded of financial capital demandPrivate savings=Private investment + Government budget deficit + Trade surplusS=I + (G – T) + (X – M) 

We assume that the point to these equations is that the national saving and investment identity always hold. When you write these relationships, it is important to engage your brain and think about what is on the supply and demand side of the financial capital market before you start your calculations.

As you can see in Figure 31.3, the Office of Management and Budget shows that the United States has consistently run budget deficits since 1977, with the exception of 1999 and 2000. What is alarming is the dramatic increase in budget deficits that has occurred since 2008, which in part reflects declining tax revenues and increased safety net expenditures due to the Great Recession. While deficits were controlled as the economy began to recover in the mid-2010s, the budget deficit increased again in 2020 during the pandemic, and forecasters expect deficits to remain high for the foreseeable future. (Recall that T is net taxes. When the government must transfer funds back to individuals for safety net expenditures like Social Security and unemployment benefits, budget deficits rise.) These deficits have implications for the future health of the U.S. economy.

This graph is a bar chart illustrating for each year whether the U.S. federal government runs a budget surplus or a budget deficit. The y-axis measures the federal surplus or deficit, in billions of dollars, from –3,500 billion dollars, or –3.5 trillion dollars, to 500 billion dollars, in increments of 500 billion dollars. The x-axis shows years, from 1952 to 2020. From 1952 to the early 1980s, the budget is either balanced, or shows a very small deficit, of no more than around 50 billion dollars. There are deficits in the 1980s and early 1990s, but from 1997 to 2001 there is a budget surplus. There are budget deficits in all the remaining years. They are over 1,000 billion dollars 2009 to 2012, then the deficits shrink to under 500 billion in 2015, then deficits grow again yearly, to nearly 1,000 billion dollars in 2019, and over 3,000 billion, or 3 trillion, dollars in 2020.
Figure 31.3 United States On-Budget, Surplus, and Deficit, 1952–2020 ($ billions) The United States has run a budget deficit for over 30 years, with the exception of 1999 and 2000. Military expenditures, entitlement programs, and the decrease in tax revenue coupled with increased safety net support during the Great Recession are major contributors to the dramatic increases in the deficit after 2008. (Source: Office of Management and Budget, https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/FYFSGDA188S)

A rising budget deficit may result in a fall in domestic investment, a rise in private savings, or a rise in the trade deficit. The following modules discuss each of these possible effects in more detail.

Citation/Attribution

This book may not be used in the training of large language models or otherwise be ingested into large language models or generative AI offerings without OpenStax's permission.

Want to cite, share, or modify this book? This book uses the Creative Commons Attribution License and you must attribute OpenStax.

Attribution information
  • If you are redistributing all or part of this book in a print format, then you must include on every physical page the following attribution:
    Access for free at https://openstax.org/books/principles-economics-3e/pages/1-introduction
  • If you are redistributing all or part of this book in a digital format, then you must include on every digital page view the following attribution:
    Access for free at https://openstax.org/books/principles-economics-3e/pages/1-introduction
Citation information

© Jul 18, 2024 OpenStax. Textbook content produced by OpenStax is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution License . The OpenStax name, OpenStax logo, OpenStax book covers, OpenStax CNX name, and OpenStax CNX logo are not subject to the Creative Commons license and may not be reproduced without the prior and express written consent of Rice University.